Translate

14 outubro 2019

Custo da Formatação de um artigo

Uma das piores partes de uma pesquisa é fazer a formatação do trabalho final. É preciso observar o espaço entre linhas, a letra solicitada, o tamanho da margem, sem falar na norma de citação e outras observações. Leva-se muito tempo nesta estimativa. Cada periódico tem sua regra, assim como cada congresso, programa de pós, etc. Além disto, algumas entidades insistem em mudar regularmente as normas ou criar novas normas para situações específicas.

Uma pesquisa realizada por cientistas canadenses encontrou o tempo que se gasta para fazer este trabalho. Usando mais de 300 respondentes, o pesquisadores descobriram o tempo por artigo submetido e a quantidade de artigos. Além disto, solicitaram o valor da renda anual. Considerando uma carga de trabalho anual de 1950 horas, a pesquisa obteve que o custo anual de formatação de artigos é de ...1.908 dólares. Por artigo, o custo seria perto de 500 dólares ou 477 dólares.

Eles também encontraram que este custo é maior para os mais idosos, para os homens e os não cientistas.

Assim, quando você estiver em uma posição de editoria de um periódico ou de um congresso, procure ser mais flexível neste aspecto.

Scientific sinkhole: The pernicious price of formatting. Allana G. LeBlanc, Joel D. Barnes, Travis J. Saunders, Mark S. Tremblay, Jean-Philippe Chaput. PLOS One September 26, 2019)

13 outubro 2019

Nobel de Economia: quem merece ?

[...]



No. 1. The New Keynesians

Not since 2011 has a prize been awarded to economists who primarily study the ups and downs of the business cycle, so we might be overdue. The obvious choice would be to award the prize for the creation of New Keynesian theory. This theory holds that recessions happen because businesses have difficulty adjusting their prices in response to economic disturbances.

Although it’s the dominant paradigm within modern academic macroeconomics, and is used by most central banks to help set monetary policy, New Keynesianism hasn’t yet received a gold medal from Sweden. One reason might be that the theory isn’t the brainchild of a single genius, but of a large group of influential figures who each added key elements. These include Michael Woodford, Stanley Fischer, Greg Mankiw, Nobuhiro Kiyotaki, Olivier Blanchard, Guillermo Calvo, Janet Yellen, David Romer and a number of others. Picking two or three to award the prize to will be hard, but it seems inevitable that the prize committee will eventually have to recognize this incredibly influential theory.

No. 2. Claudia Goldin

Before French economist Thomas Piketty ever hit the bestseller lists, Harvard University’s Claudia Goldin was writing about the rise in economic inequality. Combining the methods of labor economics and economic history, Goldin identifies increasing education as a key driver of the fall in U.S. inequality in the early 20th century, and blames a slowdown in educational attainment for the reversal of that happy trend.

Goldin has also extensively studied the changing role of women in the economy, weaving together trends like delayed childbearing, increasing education and forward-looking decision-making to create the authoritative story of how and why women entered the formal workforce. She has advocated for flexible work scheduling as a way to reduce the gender pay gap. And she has theorized that workplace gender discrimination results from men being afraid that the occupations they dominate will be devalued if women enter. In an age when society is struggling to eliminate gender inequality, Goldin’s work provides a crucial road map.

No. 3. David Card

Great changes have happened in the economics profession during the past three decades. The field has gone from a largely theoretical discipline to one firmly grounded in empirics and data. Although the transition is the work of many thousands of economists, perhaps no one has pointed the way forward as clearly as the University of California-Berkeley’s David Card. His landmark studies of low-skilled immigration and minimum wages changed the debate on those crucial issues, astonishing economists with the finding -- now corroborated by decades of follow-up research -- that neither is particularly damaging to local workers. Those results changed the world, but they represent only a small portion of Card’s extensive body of work. If anyone deserves to win a Nobel for the seismic shift that has changed the very meaning of economics research, it’s probably Card.

No. 4. Paul Milgrom

The economics Nobel tends to favor the work of pure theorists who work on the deepest problems. And few thinkers dig deeper than Stanford University’s Paul Milgrom. He was a major figure in the creation of auction theory -- probably the most empirically successful and practically useful economic theory of all time, which is now used to power everything from Google ads to federal spectrum auctions. He has also contributed deep insights to our understanding of financial markets, modeling the way that market makers interact with informed and uninformed traders, and helping to explain why trading happens in the first place. This is only the tip of the iceberg, though. Milgrom’s contributions in game theory, contract theory, labor economics, industrial organization, the economics of information and learning, and other fields are too numerous to mention or elaborate here. If he never wins the Nobel for this virtuosic career, it will be a big surprise.

No. 5. Daron Acemoglu

Daron Acemoglu is another virtuoso, but of a very different sort. Acemoglu tackles the big questions of why nations grow and develop or stagnate and decline -- the kinds of questions that rarely if ever get definitive answers. His most important thesis is that social institutions are crucial for development and don’t change much over time -- places that develop institutions based on exploiting labor and extracting resources tend to do badly over the centuries, while those that create more inclusive systems flourish. More recently, Acemoglu has tackled the question of whether automation will make humans obsolete. He has created new models of automation in which it’s possible for robots to reduce human wages, and theorized that different types of artificial intelligence could help human workers or compete with them. Beyond those topics, Acemoglu has a vast body of work, much of it dealing with difficult and expansive topics like politics, history, culture and technological change.
Fonte: aqui
[...]

Imagem relacionada

12 outubro 2019

Papel do orientador

Sobre o Nobel de Economia, é interessante que vários laureados tiveram seus pupilos também premiados. Eis uma relação:

Jan Tinbergen was an adviser of Koopmans.
Paul Samuelson was an adviser for Klein and Merton.
Kenneth Arrow advised the research of Harsanyi, Spence, Maskin, and Myerson.
Wassily Leontief advised Samuelson, Schelling, Solow, and Smith.
Richard Stone supervised the research of both Mirrlees and Deaton.
Franco Modigliani was Shiller’s adviser.
James Tobin advised Phelps.
Merton Miller advised Eugene Fama’s dissertation, and Fama advised Scholes’s.
Robert Solow supervised the work of Diamond, Akerlof, Stiglitz, and Nordhaus.
Thomas Schelling was Spence’s adviser.
Edward Prescott advised Kydland, with whom he shared the 2004 Nobel Prize.
Eric Maskin advised Tirole.
Christopher Sims advised Hansen.
Simon Kuznets supervised both Friedman and Fogel.

Quem não ganhou o Nobel de Economia (mas deveria)

Eis uma lista originária daqui

Frank Knight (1972). One of the founders of the “Chicago School of Economics,” he is best known for his 1921 book, Risk, Uncertainty and Profit.

Alvin Hansen (1975). Macroeconomist and public policy adviser, often referred to as “the American Keynes,” he is most noted for development (with Hicks) of the “investment-savings” and “liquidity preference-money supply” (IS-LM) macroeconomics model.

Oskar Morgenstern (1977). Princeton economist, coauthor of Theory of Games and Economic Behavior (1944, with John von Neumann).

Joan Robinson (1983). Cambridge economist known for her work on monopolistic competition (The Economics of Imperfect Competition, 1933) and coining the term monopsony.

Piero Sraffa (1983). Italian economist and considered the neo-Ricardian school founder owing to his Production of Commodities by Means of Commodities (1960).

Fischer Black (1995), part creator of the Black–Scholes equation on options pricing, surely would have shared the 1997 Nobel with Scholes and Merton for devising a model for the dynamics of a financial market containing derivative investment instruments.

Amos Tversky (1996). A cognitive psychologist, who undoubtedly would have shared the 2002 Nobel Prize with his friend and frequent collaborator Daniel Kahneman (and Vernon Smith).

Zvi Griliches (1999). A student of Schultz and Arnold Harberger at Chicago, he is best known for work on technological change (the diffusion of hybrid corn in particular) and econometrics.

Sherwin Rosen (2001). Labor economist with far-ranging contributions in microeconomics, he is perhaps best known for his 1981 American Economic Review article “The Economics of Superstars,” and his 1974 Journal of Political Economy article outlining how the market solves the problem of matching buyers and sellers of multidimensional goods.

John Muth (2005). Doctoral advisee of Herbert Simon, he is considered—mainly formulated on the microeconomics side—as the originator of “rational expectations” theory.

John Kenneth Galbraith (2006), long-time Harvard economist, was a prolific writer (The Affluent Society (1958), The New Industrial State (1967)), public intellectual, and liberal political activist.

Anna Schwartz (2012). A National Bureau of Economic Research monetary and banking scholar, she was a coauthor with Milton Friedman of A Monetary History of the United States, 1867-1960 (1963).

Martin Shubik (2018). A doctoral advisee of Morgenstern and collaborator with Nash, at Princeton, he was a long-time Yale professor of mathematical economics and outstanding game theorist.


To this list, one could certainly add more of their contemporaries, for example (in alphabetical order), Anthony Atkinson (2017), William Baumol (2017), Harold Demsetz (2019), Evsey Domar (1997), Rudiger Dornbusch (2002), Henry Roy Forbes Harrod (1978), Harold Hotelling (1973), Nicholas Kaldor (1986), Jacob Mincer (2006), Hyman Minsky (1996), and Ludwig von Mises (1973), among many others.

Frase

O [Nobel de Economia] é o único em que duas pessoas podem dividir um Prêmio Nobel por dizer coisas opostas


Vide o prêmio de 1972 (Myrdal e Hayek) ou de 2013 (Fama e Shiller)

Via aqui

09 outubro 2019

Monstro

Um livro de duas jornalistas, ganhadoras do Pulitzer, conta um pouco da história de Weinstein. Para que não lembra, Weinstein era um produto de cinema nos Estados Unidos, responsável por muitos filmes de sucesso e que conseguiu prêmios, como o Oscar de melhor atriz para G Paltrow, através de muita campanha publicitária (muitas vezes nem sempre "razoáveis").

Weinstein foi denunciado por assédio há meses. A pergunta que o livro She Said, de Kantor e Twohey, faz é: qual a razão de ter durado tanto tempo as maldades dele?

Um texto do The Conversation fornece uma possível resposta: a moralidade dos advogados.

O único advogado poupado do julgamento é o advogado interno do The New York Times, David McCraw .

Ele responde a uma ofensiva carta de Weinstein com a certeza de que "qualquer artigo que fizermos cumprirá nossos padrões habituais de precisão e justiça". O artigo de Kantor e Twohey é publicado no dia seguinte.

O livro levanta questões importantes sobre até que ponto a profissão de advogado foi cúmplice em ocultar uma conduta como a de Weinstein ao longo dos anos. Enquanto os advogados do livro são caricaturas, seus colegas mais banais - advogados como eu, que costumavam inserir disposições de confidencialidade em acordos de acordos - não são menos cúmplices.

Diferentemente da ética jornalística, que é rica em tradição e revigorada quando aplicada, as regras éticas legais são codificadas na lei estadual . Como resultado, os advogados não precisam concordar ou mesmo examinar o componente moral do que fazem. (...)


No final, não foram os advogados, que deveriam preservar a justiça, que conseguiram deter Weinstein, mas sim os jornalistas.

Rir é o melhor remédio